April 25, 2013
The 1 Percent’s Solution
By PAUL KRUGMAN
Economic debates rarely end with a T.K.O. But
the great policy debate of recent years between Keynesians, who advocate
sustaining and, indeed, increasing government spending in a depression, and
austerians, who demand immediate spending cuts, comes close — at least in the
world of ideas. At this point, the austerian position has imploded; not only have
its predictions about the real world failed completely, but the academic
research invoked to support that position has turned out to be riddled with
errors, omissions and dubious statistics.
Yet two big questions remain. First, how did
austerity doctrine become so influential in the first place? Second, will
policy change at all now that crucial austerian claims have become fodder for
late-night comics?
On the first question: the dominance of
austerians in influential circles should disturb anyone who likes to believe
that policy is based on, or even strongly influenced by, actual evidence. After
all, the two main studies providing the alleged intellectual justification for
austerity — Alberto Alesina and Silvia Ardagna on “expansionary austerity” and
Carmen Reinhart and Kenneth Rogoff on the dangerous debt “threshold” at 90
percent of G.D.P. — faced withering criticism almost as soon as they came out.
And the studies did not hold up under scrutiny.
By late 2010, the International Monetary Fund had reworked
Alesina-Ardagna with better data and reversed their findings,
while many economists
raised fundamental questions about Reinhart-Rogoff long before
we knew aboutthe famous Excel error. Meanwhile,
real-world events — stagnation in Ireland, the original poster child for
austerity, falling interest rates in the United States, which was supposed to
be facing an imminent fiscal crisis — quickly made nonsense of austerian
predictions.
Yet austerity maintained and even strengthened
its grip on elite opinion. Why?
Part of the answer surely lies in the widespread
desire to see economics as a morality play, to make it a tale of excess and its
consequences. We lived beyond our means, the story goes, and now we’re paying
the inevitable price. Economists can explain ad nauseam that this is wrong,
that the reason we have mass unemployment isn’t that we spent too much in the
past but that we’re spending too little now, and that this problem can and
should be solved. No matter; many people have a visceral sense that we sinned
and must seek redemption through suffering — and neither economic argument nor
the observation that the people now suffering aren’t at all the same people who
sinned during the bubble years makes much of a dent.
But it’s not just a matter of emotion versus
logic. You can’t understand the influence of austerity doctrine without talking
about class and inequality.
What, after all, do people want from economic
policy? The answer, it turns out, is that it depends on which people you ask —
a point documented in a recent research paper by the political scientists
Benjamin Page, Larry Bartels and Jason Seawright. The paper compares the policy
preferences of ordinary Americans with those of the very wealthy, and the
results are eye-opening.
Thus, the average American is somewhat worried
about budget deficits, which is no surprise given the constant barrage of
deficit scare stories in the news media, but the wealthy, by a large majority,
regard deficits as the most important problem we face. And how should the budget
deficit be brought down? The wealthy favor cutting federal spending on health
care and Social Security — that is, “entitlements” — while the public at large
actually wants to see spending on those programs rise.
You get the idea: The austerity agenda looks a
lot like a simple expression of upper-class preferences, wrapped in a facade of
academic rigor. What the top 1 percent wants becomes what economic science says
we must do.
Does a continuing depression actually serve the
interests of the wealthy? That’s doubtful, since a booming economy is generally
good for almost everyone. What is true, however, is that the years since we
turned to austerity have been dismal for workers but not at all bad for the
wealthy, who have benefited from surging profits and stock prices even as
long-term unemployment festers. The 1 percent may not actually want a weak
economy, but they’re doing well enough to indulge their prejudices.
And this makes one wonder how much difference
the intellectual collapse of the austerian position will actually make. To the
extent that we have policy of the 1 percent, by the 1 percent, for the 1
percent, won’t we just see new justifications for the same old policies?
I hope not; I’d like to believe that ideas and
evidence matter, at least a bit. Otherwise, what am I doing with my life? But I
guess we’ll see just how much cynicism is justified.
RT: LOLGOP @LOLGOP
ReplyDeleteThe only thing 1 percenters want to give to the poor these days are reasons why the poor need to be punished.
RT: Sarcasm! @comedytexts
ReplyDelete“can u not” has been my mental response to almost everything that happens these days